Guide Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective

Free download. Book file PDF easily for everyone and every device. You can download and read online Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective file PDF Book only if you are registered here. And also you can download or read online all Book PDF file that related with Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective book. Happy reading Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective Bookeveryone. Download file Free Book PDF Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective at Complete PDF Library. This Book have some digital formats such us :paperbook, ebook, kindle, epub, fb2 and another formats. Here is The CompletePDF Book Library. It's free to register here to get Book file PDF Entrepreneurship and Growth: An International Historical Perspective Pocket Guide.

Subjects Corporations -- Growth. Summary Provides an international, comparative and historical perspective, with a special focus on Mediterranean countries including Spain, Italy and Greece. Contents Machine generated contents note: I A Multinational Approach 1.

A Tale of Four Countries: II International Experiences 2. IV Some Local Cases: Minorca and Madrid 7. Includes bibliographical references pages and index. Other Form Print version Entrepreneurship and growth. View online Borrow Buy Freely available Show 0 more links With access conditions View at https: Other links Ebook Library at http: Set up My libraries How do I set up "My libraries"?

These 5 locations in All: In sum, this article brings closer together business history and management studies stressing that their different perspectives and approaches are very valuable to enriching entrepreneurship research. Innovation and Small Firms. Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. An Interdisciplinary Survey and Introduction. Smelser and Richard Swedberg , Toward a family embeddedness perspective.

Sexton and Raymond W. State of the Art and Controversies. Amatori, Franco, and Geoffrey Jones. Business History around the World. Trust within the organization. Public Service Commission of Canada. Entrepreneurship, Management, and the Structure of Payoffs. Bozeman, Barry, and Gordon Kingsley. Understanding enterprise, entrepreneurship and small business.

Past research, present findings, and future directions. Bucheli, Marcelo, and Daniel Wadhwani. Toward a Structural Theory of Action: Structure, form, and action , edited by N.

Evolution of Ideas with in the Business Strategy from Historical Perspective

Harvard Business School Press. An Introduction to Social Capital. Past trends and future directions. Cassis, Youssef, and Ioanna P. State of the art and new perspectives.


  1. .
  2. Evolution of Ideas with in the Business Strategy from Historical Perspective | OMICS International.
  3. The Search for Meaning in Organizations: Seven Practical Questions for Ethical Managers.
  4. Invisible Promises.
  5. A Game of Thrones: The Story Continues Books 1-5: A Game of Thrones, A Clash of Kings, A Storm of Swords, A Feast for Crows, A Dance with Dragons (A Song of Ice and Fire).
  6. Glitter: A Modern Fairy Tale?
  7. .

Their Relevance to Business History. Entrepreneurship and Business Culture. Studies in the Economics of Trust , vol. Casson, Mark, and Andrew Godley. Minoglou, , New York: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise. Essays in Honour of Charles Wilson , edited by D. The dynamics of industrial capitalism. From Neglect to Cooperation. The Perspective of Business History. Colli, Andrea, and Mary B.

The culture and evolution of family firms in Britain and Italy in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. The Past, the Present, and the Future. An International Journal 8 1: Coviello, Nicole, and Hugh Munro. Institutional Change and American Economic Growth. Publicaciones de la Universidad de Alicante. Dobbin, Frank, and Timothy J. Early Railroad Foundings in Massachusetts. Eckhardt, Jon, and Scott Shane.

Eisenhardt, Kathleen, and Melissa E. Elfring, Tom, and Willem Hulsink. Patterns of tie formation in emerging organizations.


  • ?
  • ?
  • The Phoenix Rises.
  • Three Weddings and a Baby (Mills & Boon Modern Heat) (Mills & Boon RIVA).
  • sTORI Telling;
  • The Endurance of Family Businesses: Innovation and Entrepreneurial Networks in Europe. The Determinants of Entrepreneurship: Human capital refers to the investments that human beings make in themselves to enhance their economic productivity. These investments can take on many forms and include not only schooling but also apprenticeship, a healthy diet, and exercise, among other possibilities.

    Some economists have even suggested that more amorphous societal factors such as trust, institutional tradition, technological know how and innovation can all be viewed as forms of human capital Temple a; Topel ; Mokyr Thus broadly defined, human capital would appear as a prime candidate for explaining much of the difference across nations and over time in output and economic growth. However, gaining much insight into the actual magnitudes and the channels of influence by which human capital might influence economic growth requires specification of both the nature and determinants of human capital and how human capital affects aggregate production of an economy.

    Much of the literature on human capital and growth makes the implicit assumption that some sort of numerical scale exists for human capital, even if multidimensional and even if unobservable. This in turn implies that it is meaningful to relate levels and changes of human capital to levels of income per capita and rates of economic growth. Given the multiplicity of factors that influence human knowledge and skill and in turn how these influence labor productivity, difficulties would seem likely to arise with attempts to measure aggregate human capital similar to those that have arisen with attempts to specify and measure the nature of human intelligence.

    Get this edition

    Woessmann , provides useful surveys of some of the issues involved in attempting to specify human capital at the aggregate level appropriate for relating it to economic growth. One can distinguish between approaches to the measurement of human capital that focus on schooling, as in the discussion above, and those that take a broader view. Broad view approaches try to capture all investments that may have improved human productivity from whatever source, including not just schooling but other productivity enhancing investments, such as on-the-job training.

    The basic premise of broad view approaches is that for an aggregate economy, the income going to labor over and above what that labor would earn if it were paid the income of an unskilled worker can be viewed as human capital. This measure can be constructed in various ways including as a ratio using unskilled labor earnings as the denominator as in Mulligan and Sala-I-Martin or using the share of labor income not going as compensation for unskilled labor as in Crafts and Mitch Mulligan and Sala-I-Martin point to some of the major index number problems that can arise in using this approach to aggregate heterogeneous workers.

    Crafts and Mitch find that for Britain during its late eighteenth and early nineteenth century industrial revolution between one-sixth and one-fourth of income per capita can be attributed to human capital measured as the share of labor income not going as compensation for unskilled labor. One approach that has been taken recently to estimate the role of human capital differences in explaining international differences in income per capita is to consider changes in immigrant earnings between origin and destination countries along with differences between immigrant and native workers in the destination country.

    Olson suggested that the large increase in earnings of immigrants commonly observed in moving from a low income to a high income country points to a small role for human capital in explaining the wide variation in per capita income across countries. Hendricks has used differences between immigrant and native earnings in the U.

    One possible source of such skills is through the informal acquisition of human capital through on-the-job experience. Insofar as work has been common from early adolescence onwards, the issue arises of why the aggregate stock of skills acquired through experience would vary over time and thus influence rates of economic growth. Some types of on-the-job experience which contribute to economic productivity, such as apprenticeship, may entail an opportunity cost and aggregate trends in skill accumulation will be influenced by societal willingness to incur such opportunity costs.

    Insofar as schooling continues through adolescence, this can interfere with the accumulation of workforce experience. DeLong, Goldin and Katz note the tradeoff between rising average years of schooling completed and decreasing years of labor force experience in influencing labor force quality of the U.

    Connolly has found that informal experience played a relatively greater role in Southern economic growth than for other regions of the United States. Hansen has also distinguished the academically-oriented secondary schooling the United States developed in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century from the vocationally-oriented schooling and apprenticeship system that Germany developed over the same time period.

    Education and Economic Growth in Historical Perspective

    Goldin argues that in the United States the educational system developed general abilities suitable for the greater opportunities for geographical and occupational mobility that prevailed there, while specific vocational training was more suitable for the more restricted mobility opportunities in Germany. Little evidence exists on whether long-term trends in informal opportunities for skill acquisition have influenced growth rates. Economists commonly claim that education yields benefits to society over and above the impact on labor market productivity perceived by the person receiving the education.

    These benefits can include impacts on economic productivity, such as impacts on technological advance. They can also include non-labor market benefits. Thus McMahon , 11 in his assessment of the social benefits of education includes not only direct effects on economic productivity but also impacts on a population growth rates and health b democratization, political stability, and human rights, c the environment, d reduction of poverty and inequality, e crime and drug use, and f labor force participation.

    While these effects may appear to involve primarily non-market activity and thus would not be reflected in national output measures and growth rates, factors such as political stability, democratization, population growth, and health have obvious consequences for prospects for long-term growth. However, allowance should be made for the simultaneous influence of the distribution of political power and life expectancy on societal investments in schooling. For the period since , numerous studies have employed cross country variation in various estimates of human capital and income per capita to directly estimate the impact of human capital on levels of income per capita and growth.

    A central goal of many such estimates is to see if there are externalities to education on output over and above the private returns estimated from micro data. The results have been conflicting and this has been attributed not only to problems of measurement error but also to differences in specification of human capital and its impact on growth.

    There does not appear to be strong evidence of large positive externalities to human capital Temple a. Furthermore, McMahon reports some empirical specifications which yield substantial indirect long-run effects. For the period before , limits on the availability of data on schooling and income have limited the use of this empirical regression approach. Thus, any discussion of the impact of externalities of education on production is considerably more conjectural. The central role of government, religious, and philanthropic agencies in the provision of schooling suggests the presence of externalities.

    Politicians and educators more frequently justified government and philanthropic provision of schooling by its impacts on religious and moral behavior than by any market failure resulting in sub-optimal provision of schooling from the standpoint of maximizing labor productivity. Thus, Adam Smith in his discussion of mass schooling in The Wealth of Nations, places more emphasis on its value to the state in enhancing orderliness and decency while reducing the propensity to popular superstition than on its immediate value in enhancing the economic productivity of the individual worker.

    The approaches considered thus far relate changes in educational attainment of the labor force to changes in output per worker. The argument for doing so is that a high but unchanging level of educational attainment should contribute to growth by facilitating creativity, innovation and adaptation to change as well as facilitating the ongoing maintenance and improvement of skill in the workforce. Topel has argued that there may not be any fundamental difference between the two types of approach insofar as ongoing sources of productivity advance and adaptation to change could be viewed as reflecting ongoing improvements in human capital.

    The paucity of data on schooling attainment has limited the empirical examination of the relationship between levels of human capital and economic growth for periods before the late twentieth century. However, Sandberg has argued, based on a descriptive comparison of economies in various categories, that those with high levels of schooling in subsequently experienced faster rates of economic growth.

    History of Entrepreneurship

    Bowman and Anderson , a much earlier study based on international evidence for the mid-twentieth century, can be interpreted in the spirit of relating levels of education to subsequent levels of income growth. Their reading of the cross-country relationship between literacy rates and per capita income at mid-twentieth-century was that a threshold of 40 percent adult literacy was required for a country to have a per capita income above dollars. Some have ahistorically projected back this literacy threshold to earlier centuries although the Bowman and Anderson proposal was intended to apply to mid-twentieth century development patterns.

    The mechanisms by which the level of schooling would influence the rate of economic growth are problematic to establish. One can distinguish two general possibilities. One would be that higher levels of educational attainment facilitate adaptation and responsiveness to change throughout the workforce. This would be especially important where a large percentage of workers are in decision making positions such as an economy composed largely of small farmers and other small enterprises. The finding of Foster and Rosenzweig for late twentieth century India that the rate of return to schooling is higher during periods of more rapid technological advance in agriculture would be consistent with this.

    Likewise, Nilsson et al find that literacy was important for nineteenth-century Swedish farmers in dealing with enclosure, an institutional change. The other possibility is that higher levels of educational attainment increase the potential pool from which an elite group responsible for innovation can be recruited. Recently, Labuske and Baten have found that international rates of patenting are related to secondary enrollment rates.

    Two issues have arisen in the recent theoretical literature regarding specifying relationships between the level of human capital and rates of economic growth. This specification of the impact of the initial level of human capital allows for ongoing and unbounded growth of human capital and through this its ongoing contribution to economic growth.

    Freely available

    Such ongoing growth of human capital could occur through improvements in the quality of schooling or through enhanced improvements in learning from parents and other informal settings. While it might be plausible to suppose that improved education of teachers will enhance their effectiveness with learners, it seems less plausible to suppose that this enhanced effectiveness will increase unbounded in proportion to initial levels of education Lord , A second issue is that insofar as higher levels of human capital contribute to economic growth through increases in research and development activity and innovative activity more generally, one would expect the presence of scale effects.

    Economies with larger populations holding constant their level of human capital per person should benefit from more overall innovative activity simply because they have more people engaged in innovative activity. Jones has pointed out that such scale effects seem implausible if one looks at the time series relationship between rates of economic growth and those engaged in innovative activity.

    In recent decades the growth of the number of scientists, engineers, and others engaged in innovative activity has far outstripped the actual growth of productivity and other indicators of direct impact on innovation. Thus, one should allow for diminishing returns in the relationship between levels of education and technological advance. Thus, as with schooling externalities, considering the impact of levels of education on growth offers numerous channels of influence leaving the challenge for the historian of ascertaining their quantitative importance in the past.

    This survey has considered some of the basic ways in which the rise of mass education has contributed to economic growth in recent centuries. Given their potential influence on labor productivity, levels and changes in schooling and of human capital more generally have the potential for explaining a large share of increases in per capita output over time. However, increases in mass schooling seem to explain a major share of economic growth only over relatively short periods of time, with a more modest impact over longer time horizons.

    In some situations, such as the United States in the twentieth century, it appears that improvements in the schooling of the labor force have made substantial contributions to economic growth. Yet schooling should not be seen as either a necessary or sufficient condition for generating economic growth.

    Factors other than education can contribute to economic growth and in their absence, it is not clear that schooling in itself can contribute to economic growth. Moreover, there are likely limits on the extent to which average years of schooling of the labor force can expand, although improvement in the quality of schooling is not so obviously bounded. Perhaps the most obvious avenue through which education has contributed to economic growth is by expanding the rate of technological change. But as has been noted, there are numerous other possible channels of influence ranging from political stability and property rights to life expectancy and fertility.

    The diversity of these channels point to both the challenges and the opportunities in examining the historical connections between education and economic growth. Aaronson, Daniel and Daniel Sullivan. Abramovitz, Moses and Paul David. Engerman and Robert E. Cambridge University Press, Evidence from the Cotton Textile Industry, Historical and Comparative Perspectives. The Industrial Revolution, Oxford University Press, Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive.

    Evidence from Aggregate Cross-country Data. The Stretch-Out at Lowell, Bils, Mark and Peter J. Too Much or Too Little? An Introduction to the Economics of Education. Bowman, Mary Jean and C. Britain, the United States and Germany, David and Mark Thomas. Columbia University Press, A Separate but Unequal Story.

    The Industrial Revolution Reconsidered. Davies, James and John Whalley. How Important Is Human Capital? Douglas Bernheim and John B. University of Chicago Press, Bradford, Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Lindsay, and Pietro S. Brookings Institution Press, Committee for Economic Development, Why Growth Rates Differ: Postwar Experience in Nine Western Countries.

    Foreman-Peck, James and Pedro Lains. Evidence from the Green Revolution. Galor, Oded and Daniel Tsiddon. Galor, Oded and Omer Moav. Virtues of the Past.

    Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence F.